Product Code Database
Example Keywords: apple -ink $36-133
barcode-scavenger
   » » Wiki: Maximum Theorem
Tag Wiki 'Maximum Theorem'.
Tag

The maximum theorem provides conditions for the continuity of an optimized function and the set of its maximizers with respect to its parameters. The statement was first proven by in 1959.

(2025). 9780691117683, Princeton University Press. .
The theorem is primarily used in mathematical economics and .


Statement of theorem
Maximum Theorem. The original reference is the Maximum Theorem in Chapter 6, Section 3 Famously, or perhaps infamously, Berge only considers Hausdorff topological spaces and only allows those compact sets which are themselves Hausdorff spaces. He also requires that upper hemicontinuous correspondences be compact-valued. These properties have been clarified and disaggregated in later literature.Compare with Theorem 17.31 in
(2025). 9783540295860, Springer. .
This is given for arbitrary topological spaces. They also consider the possibility that f may only be defined on the graph of C.
Compare with Theorem 3.5 in They consider the case that \Theta and X are Hausdorff spaces.Theorem 3.6 in
(1990). 9780521336055, Cambridge University Press.
Let X and \Theta be topological spaces, f:X\times\Theta\to\mathbb{R} be a continuous function on the X \times \Theta, and C:\Theta\rightrightarrows X be a compact-valued correspondence such that C(\theta) \ne \emptyset for all \theta \in \Theta. Define the marginal function (or value function) f^* : \Theta \to \mathbb{R} by

f^*(\theta)=\sup\{f(x, \theta) : x\in C(\theta)\}

and the set of maximizers C^* : \Theta \rightrightarrows X by

C^*(\theta)= \mathrm{arg}\max\{f(x,\theta) : x \in C(\theta)\} = \{x \in C(\theta) : f(x, \theta) = f^*(\theta)\} .

If C is continuous (i.e. both upper and lower ) at \theta, then the value function f^* is continuous, and the set of maximizers C^* is upper-hemicontinuous with nonempty and compact values. As a consequence, the \sup may be replaced by \max.


Variants
The maximum theorem can be used for minimization by considering the function -f instead.


Interpretation
The theorem is typically interpreted as providing conditions for a parametric optimization problem to have continuous solutions with regard to the parameter. In this case, \Theta is the parameter space, f(x,\theta) is the function to be maximized, and C(\theta) gives the constraint set that f is maximized over. Then, f^*(\theta) is the maximized value of the function and C^* is the set of points that maximize f.

The result is that if the elements of an optimization problem are sufficiently continuous, then some, but not all, of that continuity is preserved in the solutions.


Proof
Throughout this proof we will use the term neighborhood to refer to an containing a particular point. We preface with a preliminary lemma, which is a general fact in the calculus of correspondences. Recall that a correspondence is closed if its graph is closed.

Lemma. Compare with Theorem 7 in Chapter 6, Section 1 of Berge assumes that the underlying spaces are Hausdorff and employs this property for X (but not for C) in his proof.Compare with Proposition 2.46 in They assume implicitly that \Theta and X are Hausdorff spaces, but their proof is general.Compare with Corollary 17.18 in

(2025). 9783540295860, Springer. .
This is given for arbitrary topological spaces, but the proof relies on the machinery of topological nets. If A, B : \Theta \rightrightarrows X are correspondences, A is upper hemicontinuous and compact-valued, and B is closed, then A \cap B : \Theta \rightrightarrows X defined by (A \cap B) (\theta) = A(\theta) \cap B(\theta) is upper hemicontinuous.

Let \theta \in \Theta, and suppose G is an open set containing (A\cap B)(\theta). If A(\theta) \subseteq G, then the result follows immediately. Otherwise, observe that for each x \in A(\theta) \setminus G we have x \notin B(\theta), and since B is closed there is a neighborhood U_x \times V_x of (\theta, x) in which x' \notin B(\theta') whenever (\theta', x') \in U_x \times V_x. The collection of sets \{G\} \cup \{V_x : x \in A(\theta) \setminus G\} forms an open cover of the compact set A(\theta), which allows us to extract a finite subcover G, V_{x_1}, \dots, V_{x_n}. By upper hemicontinuity, there is a neighborhood U_\theta of \theta such that A(U_\theta)\subseteq G \cup V_{x_1} \cup \dots \cup V_{x_n}. Then whenever \theta' \in U_\theta\cap U_{x_1} \cap \dots \cap U_{x_n}, we have A(\theta') \subseteq G \cup V_{x_1} \cup \dots \cup V_{x_n}, and so (A \cap B)(\theta') \subseteq G. This completes the proof. \square

The continuity of f^* in the maximum theorem is the result of combining two independent theorems together.

Theorem 1. Compare with Theorem 2 in Chapter 6, Section 3 of Berge's argument is essentially the one presented here, but he again uses auxiliary results proven with the assumptions that the underlying spaces are Hausdorff.Compare with Proposition 3.1 in They work exclusively with Hausdorff spaces, and their proof again relies on topological nets. Their result also allows for f to take on the values \pm \infty.Compare with Lemma 17.30 in

(2025). 9783540295860, Springer. .
They consider arbitrary topological spaces, and use an argument based on topological nets. If f is upper semicontinuous and C is upper hemicontinuous, nonempty and compact-valued, then f^* is upper semicontinuous.

Fix \theta \in \Theta, and let \varepsilon > 0 be arbitrary. For each x \in C(\theta), there exists a neighborhood U_x \times V_x of (\theta, x) such that whenever (\theta', x') \in U_x \times V_x, we have f(x', \theta') < f(x, \theta) + \varepsilon. The set of neighborhoods \{V_x : x \in C(\theta)\} covers C(\theta), which is compact, so V_{x_1}, \dots, V_{x_n} suffice. Furthermore, since C is upper hemicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U' of \theta such that whenever \theta' \in U' it follows that C(\theta') \subseteq \bigcup_{k=1}^{n} V_{x_k}. Let U = U' \cap U_{x_1} \cap \dots \cap U_{x_n}. Then for all \theta' \in U, we have f(x', \theta') < f(x_k, \theta) + \varepsilon for each x' \in C(\theta'), as x' \in V_{x_k} for some k. It follows that

f^*(\theta') = \sup_{x' \in C(\theta')} f(x', \theta') < \max_{k=1, \dots, n} f(x_k, \theta) + \varepsilon \leq f^*(\theta) + \varepsilon,

which was desired. \square

Theorem 2. Compare with Theorem 1 in Chapter 6, Section 3 of The argument presented here is essentially his.Compare with Proposition 3.3 in They work exclusively with Hausdorff spaces, and their proof again relies on topological nets. Their result also allows for f to take on the values \pm \infty.Compare with Lemma 17.29 in

(2025). 9783540295860, Springer. .
They consider arbitrary topological spaces and use an argument involving topological nets. If f is lower semicontinuous and C is lower hemicontinuous, then f^* is lower semicontinuous.

Fix \theta \in \Theta, and let \varepsilon > 0 be arbitrary. By definition of f^*, there exists x \in C(\theta) such that f^*(\theta) < f(x,\theta) + \frac{\varepsilon}{2}. Now, since f is lower semicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U_1 \times V of (\theta, x) such that whenever (\theta', x') \in U_1 \times V we have f(x, \theta) < f(x', \theta') + \frac{\varepsilon}{2}. Observe that C(\theta) \cap V \ne \emptyset (in particular, x \in C(\theta) \cap V). Therefore, since C is lower hemicontinuous, there exists a neighborhood U_2 such that whenever \theta' \in U_2 there exists x' \in C(\theta') \cap V. Let U = U_1 \cap U_2. Then whenever \theta' \in U there exists x' \in C(\theta') \cap V, which implies

f^*(\theta) < f(x, \theta) + \frac{\varepsilon}{2} < f(x', \theta') + \varepsilon \leq f^*(\theta') + \varepsilon

which was desired. \square

Under the hypotheses of the Maximum theorem, f^* is continuous. It remains to verify that C^* is an upper hemicontinuous correspondence with compact values. Let \theta \in \Theta. To see that C^*(\theta) is nonempty, observe that the function f_\theta : C(\theta) \to \mathbb{R} by f_\theta(x) = f(x, \theta) is continuous on the compact set C(\theta). The Extreme Value theorem implies that C^*(\theta) is nonempty. In addition, since f_\theta is continuous, it follows that C^*(\theta) a closed subset of the compact set C(\theta), which implies C^*(\theta) is compact. Finally, let D : \Theta \rightrightarrows X be defined by D(\theta) = \{x \in X : f(x, \theta) = f^*(\theta)\}. Since f is a continuous function, D is a closed correspondence. Moreover, since C^*(\theta) = C(\theta) \cap D(\theta), the preliminary Lemma implies that C^* is upper hemicontinuous. \square


Variants and generalizations
A natural generalization from the above results gives sufficient local conditions for f^* to be continuous and C^* to be nonempty, compact-valued, and upper semi-continuous.

If in addition to the conditions above, f is in x for each \theta and C is convex-valued, then C^* is also convex-valued. If f is strictly quasiconcave in x for each \theta and C is convex-valued, then C^* is single-valued, and thus is a continuous function rather than a correspondence.

If f is in X \times \Theta and C has a graph, then f^* is concave and C^* is convex-valued. Similarly to above, if f is strictly concave, then C^* is a continuous function.

(1996). 9780521497701, Cambridge University Press. .

It is also possible to generalize Berge's theorem to non-compact correspondences if the objective function is K-inf-compact.Theorem 1.2 in


Examples
Consider a utility maximization problem where a consumer makes a choice from their budget set. Translating from the notation above to the standard consumer theory notation,
  • X=\mathbb{R}_+^l is the space of all bundles of l commodities,
  • \Theta=\mathbb{R}_{++}^l \times \mathbb{R}_{++} represents the price vector of the commodities p and the consumer's wealth w,
  • f(x,\theta)=u(x) is the consumer's , and
  • C(\theta)=B(p,w)=\{x \,|\, px \leq w\} is the consumer's .

Then,

  • f^*(\theta)=v(p,w) is the indirect utility function and
  • C^*(\theta)=x(p,w) is the Marshallian demand.

Proofs in general equilibrium theory often apply the Brouwer or Kakutani fixed-point theorems to the consumer's demand, which require compactness and continuity, and the maximum theorem provides the sufficient conditions to do so.


See also
  • Brouwer fixed point theorem
  • Kakutani fixed point theorem for correspondences
  • Michael selection theorem


Notes

Page 1 of 1
1
Page 1 of 1
1

Account

Social:
Pages:  ..   .. 
Items:  .. 

Navigation

General: Atom Feed Atom Feed  .. 
Help:  ..   .. 
Category:  ..   .. 
Media:  ..   .. 
Posts:  ..   ..   .. 

Statistics

Page:  .. 
Summary:  .. 
1 Tags
10/10 Page Rank
5 Page Refs